2.2 — Production in the Short Run & Long Run — Class Content

Wednesday, March 2, 2022

Overview

Today we continue with setting up the second stage of the firm’s problem, the cost-minimization problem, where firms choose inputs \((l,k)\) that minimize total cost \((wl+rk)\) in order to produce the optimal amount of output \(q^*\). For now, we are merely assuming the amount of output that is optimal, later we will explicitly solve for it as our first stage (profit maximization problem).

In doing so, we need to split up production activity into the short-run, where firms cannot change all inputs (we traditionally assume capital is fixed \(\bar{k}\) and firms can only change labor \(l)\), and the long run, where firms can change all inputs. We discuss short run production and associated input-based metrics: marginal product and average product.

In the long-run, firms can choose many combinations of inputs \((l,k)\) that yield a desired output. We introduce two tools that will remind you a lot like the tools from consumer theory: (1) an isoquant curve1 that, similar to an indifference curve, contains all the combinations of inputs that yield the same output, and (2) an isocost line2 that, similar to a budget constraint, contains all the combinations of inputs that are the same total cost. We discuss some properties about each of these things and do some examples in anticipation of putting these tools together in the next class to solve the problem.

For some students, it takes this second time around with the tools of consumer theory for them to finally “click,” and that’s okay!

Readings

  • Ch. 6.2-6.4 in Goolsbee, Levitt, and Syverson, 2019

Slides

Below, you can find the slides in two formats. Clicking the image will bring you to the html version of the slides in a new tab. Note while in going through the slides, you can type h to see a special list of viewing options, and type o for an outline view of all the slides.

The lower button will allow you to download a PDF version of the slides. I suggest printing the slides beforehand and using them to take additional notes in class (not everything is in the slides)!

2.2-slides

Download as PDF

Appendix

Derivation of MRTS Equation (as ratio of marginal products)

Consider a movement along an isoquant curve, how would this change affect output? There will be a change in \(l\) and a change in \(k\), and multiplying the marginal product of each, and adding these together will give us our total change in output. But we know that if we are on the same isoquant curve, moving along the curve will not change output (all points on the curve are defined as having the same output!). So rearrange the equation as follows:

\[\begin{align*} MP_l \Delta l+MP_k\Delta k&= \Delta q && \text{Measuring change in output} \\ MP_l \Delta l+MP_k\Delta k&=0 && \text{But change in output is 0}\\ MP_k \Delta k&= -MP_{l} \Delta l && \text{Subtracting l terms}\\ \underbrace{\frac{\Delta k}{\Delta l}}_{MRTS} &= -\frac{MP_{l}}{MP_{k}} && \text{Dividing to get like terms on each side}\\ \end{align*}\]

Notice rise over run, \(\frac{\Delta k}{\Delta l}\), is the slope, which we have defined as the marginal rate of technical substitution (MRTS). \(\blacksquare\)

Solving the Firm’s Problem in One Step

Traditionally, it is easier if we break the firm’s profit maximization problem into two stages:

  1. The firm’s profit maximization problem:
  • Choose: \(<\) Output: \(q\) \(>\)
  • To Maximize: \(<\) Profit: \(\pi=pq-C(q)\) \(>\)
  • written mathematically: \[\max_{q \geq 0}pq-C(q)\]
  1. The firm’s cost minimization problem:
  • Choose: \(<\) Inputs: \(l,k\) \(>\)
  • To Minimize: \(<\) Total cost: \(C(q)=wl+rk\) \(>\)
  • Subject to: \(<\) Producing optimal output: \(q^*=f(k,l)\) \(>\)
  • written mathematically: \[\min_{l,k \geq 0}pq-C(q)\] \[s.t. y^*=f(k,l)\]

We proceed in class with the second stage first, and then the first stage. However, this appendix shows that the problem can be solved in a single stage. For simplicity, we look at the short run, where there is a single input \(l\) that can be chosen \((\bar{k}\) is fixed).

The firm’s profit maximization problem:

  • Choose: \(<\) Input and Output: \(l,q\) \(>\)
  • To Maximize: \(<\) Profit: \(\pi=pq-wl\) \(>\)
  • Subject to: \(<\) Technology: \(q=f(\bar{k},l)\) \(>\)
  • Written mathematically: \[\max_{l,q \geq 0}pq-wl\] \[s.t. q=f(\bar{k},l)\]

Objective: Maximize Profits

The objective function is trying to maximize profits. So we need to think about different levels (“contour lines”) of profit that correspond to combinations of input and output (at constant prices).3

A firm earns profits (\(\pi\)) as revenues minus costs: \[\pi=pq-wl\] Where - \(q\): quantity of output - \(p\): price of output - \(w\): price of input (wage) - \(l\): quantity of input (labor)

Imagine different amounts of input and output that would generate the same profit. We can think of an isoprofit line as having the equation above.

However, it’s easier if we graph it as output in terms of input (our two axes for drawing the production function): \[\begin{align*} \pi &=pq-wl\\ \pi+wl&=pq\\ \frac{\pi}{p}+\frac{w}{p}l&=q\\ \end{align*}\]

For these example isoprofit lines, since the price of our input \((w)\) is $1, and the price of output \((p)\) is $2, the slope of each of the isoprofit lines is positive \(0.5\).

Constraint: Technology

The constraint is what is technologically feasible for the firm to produce, according to its production function. We need to make a few assumptions about production functions in order to get an optimum solution:

  1. \(q>0\): firms always produce a positive amount
  2. \(\frac{dq}{d l}>0\): The more inputs used, the more output produced (the marginal product, i.e. the slope of production function, i.e. it’s first derivative, is positive)
  3. \(\frac{d^2q}{d l^2}<0\): Diminishing marginal productivity (production increases at a decreasing rate, i.e. the second derivative of the production function is negative)

These assumptions generate decreasing returns to scale in production: doubling input produces less than double output. These assumptions give us a mathematically-easy answer to find, but not all production fits these assumptions. A production function that fits these assumptions would look like this:

Solving the Problem

Essentially, we are trying to find the highest profit line tangent to our production function:

At a tangency, the slopes of the two functions are equal. The slope of the isoprofit lines we know are \(\frac{w}{p}\). The slope of the production function is the marginal product (of labor). So at the point of tangency: \[\begin{align*} \text{Slope of production function} &= \text{Slope of Isoprofit line}\\ \mathbf{MP_l}&\mathbf{=\frac{w}{p}}\\ \end{align*}\]

The Firm’s Supply and Demand Functions

The Geometry of Short-Run Production

This appendix explores the geometry of production functions in the short run. From the common law of diminishing returns (sometimes called “the law of variable proportions”), with constant technology, increasing the use of one factor (e.g. \(l)\), holding other factors constant (e.g. \(\bar{k})\), will ultimately experience diminishing returns. We often break up short-run production into three stages, based on the type of returns to increasing the use of one factor: increasing, decreasing, and negative.

I. Increasing Returns

In Stage I, labor experiences increasing returns. Both the marginal and the average product of labor are positive and (mostly) increasing. That is to say, output is increasing at an increasing rate when more labor is added, and the productivity per worker increases. For the example above, Stage I occurs over the range of 0-6 workers.

Intuitively, increasing returns means that output increases at an increasing rate. This is not the same, but you can think of this almost like exponential growth – just by adding a few more units of input we can get massive amounts of output. If this held forever, we could grow the entire world’s supply of food in a single flower pot!

Note that at 4 workers, marginal product reaches a maximum. Beyond this point, marginal product remains positive but begins to decrease. Looking at the production function, at 4 workers, the production function is at an inflection point. After 4 workers, the production function continues to increase, but now at a decreasing rate.

Geometrically, what this means is that between 0-4 workers, the production function is convex (a line connecting two points is above the function), between 4-6 workers, the production function is concave (a line connecting two points is below the function), the inflection point at 4 is where it switches between convex and concave.

Stage I ends not at 4 laborers, where marginal product is maximized, but at 6 workers, where the marginal product and average product intersect (are equal).

In practice, most firms breeze through Stage I very quickly. Naturally, if firms can boost output a lot, and cheaply, just by adding a worker or two, they will keep hiring workers and hiring workers…

II. Decreasing Returns

In Stage II, labor experiences diminishing returns. As we discussed with the law of diminishing returns, this will eventually happen to all factors of production if you keep adding them (holding other factors constant). Now, output is increasing, but at a decreasing rate. Adding more workers will increase output, but by progressively less and less, and each worker also is less productive on average, since both average and marginal product is declining (though total product is increasing). For the example above, Stage II occurs over the range of 6-8 workers.

Stage II ends at 8 workers, where the marginal product falls to zero.

In practice, most firms operate in Stage II, so this range is sometimes called the ``economic region’’ of short run production. We have seen that it is in the interest of a firm to keep adding labor during Stage I. We will next see that it is disadvantageous for a firm to keep adding labor beyond Stage II. Hence, the optimal amount of labor is often somewhere in Stage II.

III. Negative Returns

In Stage III, labor experiences negative returns, that is, adding labor actually decreases output! Here we have the “too many cooks in the kitchen” phenomenon. For the example above, Stage III happens when the firm is using 8 or more workers. We can see that the marginal product is negative, and average product continues to decline, as does output.

Recall diminishing returns implies that we are adding labor but holding all other factors (e.g. capital) constant. It is possible to increase the number of workers beyond 8 and still increase output, but that would require an increase in capital. If we do not increase capital, then by continually adding labor we will eventually hit diminishing (and negative) returns.

Stage Output \(MP_l\) \(AP_l\)
I \(\uparrow\) at \(\uparrow\) rate, then \(\uparrow\) at \(\downarrow\) rate \(\uparrow\), then \(\downarrow\) \(\uparrow\)
II \(\uparrow\) at \(\downarrow\) rate \(\downarrow\) \(\downarrow\)
III \(\downarrow\) Negative \(\downarrow\)

The Relationship Between Marginal and Average

There is a consistent relationship between any marginal magnitude and any average magnitude. We will see this when we talk about production, about costs, revenues, profits, etc.

When the marginal is greater than the average, the average is increasing because the marginal “pulls up” the average. When the marginal is less than the average, the average is decreasing because the marginal “pulls down” the average. Therefore, average is neither increasing nor decreasing (reaches a maximum/minimum) when the marginal equals the average.

Think of your grades or your GPA. Suppose your average is a B, and you get back a (marginal) grade that is an A. Since the marginal is higher than the average, this pulls up your average. Suppose instead you get back a (marginal) grade that is a C. Since the marginal is lower than the average, this pulls down your average.

Case \(AP_l\)
\(MP_l > AP_l\) \(\uparrow\)
\(MP_l = AP_l\) Maximized
\(MP_l < AP_l\) \(\downarrow\)

Look at the lower panel of the figure above and you can see, in Stage I, \(MP_l>AP_l\) and thus \(AP_l\) is increasing. The transition to Stage II occurs where \(MP_l=AP_l\) and thus \(AP_l\) reaches its maximum. In Stage III, \(MP_l<AP_l\) and thus \(AP_l\) is falling.

If these graphs looks vaguely familiar, cost curves (total cost, marginal cost, average cost) are monetized reciprocals of product curves (total product, marginal product, average product). Here is a proof (that will make sense a few lessons from now):

\[MC(q) = \frac{ \partial VC(q)}{\partial q} = w \frac{\partial l}{\partial q}= w \frac{1}{MP_l}\]

\[ AVC(q) = \frac{ \partial VC}{\partial q} = w \frac{l}{q}= w \frac{1}{AP_l} \]

Elasticity of Substitution

How easy is it to substitute between labor and capital (or any inputs)? Along a single isoquant, the rate of technical substitution (MRTS) will diminish as we move to the right (more labor, less capital, i.e. the capital/labor ratio, \(\frac{k}{l}\) decreases). The elasticity of substitution (often written \(\sigma)\), measures the degree of responsiveness: \[\sigma=\cfrac{\% \Delta \left(\frac{k}{l}\right)}{\% \Delta MRTS}=\cfrac{\% \Delta \left(\frac{k}{l}\right)}{\% \Delta \frac{MP_L}{MP_K}}\]

We can measure the elasticity of substitution \(\sigma\) for four common types of production functions: 1. Linear production functions \((\sigma=\infty)\) \[q=f(l,k)=\alpha k+\beta l\] 2. Fixed proportions (i.e. perfect complements, known as “Leontief” production functions): \(\sigma=0\) \[q=\min\{\alpha k, \beta l\} \quad \alpha, \beta >0 \] 3. Cobb-Douglas (\(\sigma = 1)\) \[\begin{align*} q=f(k,l)&=Ak^\alpha l^\beta \\ f(tk,tl) &= A(tk)^\alpha (tl)^\beta \\ &= At^{\alpha + \beta}k^\alpha l ^\beta \\ &=t^{\alpha+\beta}Ak^\alpha l^\beta \\ &=t^{\alpha+\beta}f(k,l)\\ \end{align*}\]

Hence, if \(\alpha+\beta=1\) (constant returns to scale),

  1. Constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production function: \[q=f(k,l)=[k^\rho + l^\rho]^{\frac{\gamma}{\rho}}\]

Where \(\sigma=\frac{1}{1-\rho}\) - For \(\gamma >1\): increasing returns - For \(\gamma <1\): decreasing returns

Incorporates all three previous cases: 1. Linear: \(\rho=1\)

\[[k + l]^{\gamma}\]

  1. Fixed proportions: \(\rho = -\infty\)

\[[k^{-\infty} + l^{-\infty}]^{\frac{\gamma}{-\infty}}\]

  1. Cobb-Douglas: \(\rho=0\)

\[[k^{0} + l^{0}]^{\frac{\gamma}{0}}\]


  1. Call it an output curve to remember it better.↩︎

  2. Call it just a cost line to remember it better.↩︎

  3. This is similar to finding indifference curves for consumers’ attempting to maximize their utility function (by finding the highest indifference curve for their budget).↩︎

Previous
Next