2.5 — Short Run Profit Maximization — Class Content

Wednesday, March 23, 2022

Problem Set 4 is due by the end of the day Friday April 1.

Exam 2 will be on Monday April 4.

Overview

Today we briefly discuss revenues before we put them together to solve the firm’s profit maximization problem. We focus on the short run, where the firm incurs fixed costs and must stay in the market regardless. We derive the firm’s (inverse) supply curve.

Next class will be about the long run, and finish up unit 2.

Readings

  • Chs. 8.1-8.3 in Goolsbee, Levitt, and Syverson, 2019

Slides

Below, you can find the slides in two formats. Clicking the image will bring you to the html version of the slides in a new tab. Note while in going through the slides, you can type h to see a special list of viewing options, and type o for an outline view of all the slides.

The lower button will allow you to download a PDF version of the slides. I suggest printing the slides beforehand and using them to take additional notes in class (not everything is in the slides)!

2.5-slides

Download as PDF

Practice

Today we will be working on practice problems. Answers will be posted later on that page.

Assignments

Problem Set 4 Due Fri Apr 1

Problem set 4 (on classes 2.4-2.6) is due by the end of the day Friday, April 1 by upload to Blackboard Assignments.

Appendix

Common Cost Assumptions

Economists often make simple assumptions about costs to illustrate key concepts without marring the analysis with unnecessary complexity. This also makes graphs quite easy to point to and calculate key areas, such as profits or deadweight losses.

One common set of cost assumptions is the following:

  1. A firm has no fixed costs
  2. A firm has constant marginal costs, \(MC(q)=c\) where \(c\geq0\)

If this is the case, then we can show that average costs will be equal to marginal costs, i.e. \(MC=AC=AVC=c\).

Since marginal cost is the first derivative of the total cost function, integrating a marginal cost function \(MC=c\) leaves with with a total cost function of \(C(q)=cq\).1 If this is the case, then we can find the average cost:

\[\begin{align*} C(q)&=cq\\ AC(q)=\frac{C(q)}{q}&=\frac{cq}{q}\\ AC(q)&=c\\ \end{align*}\]

Another common set of cost assumptions is the following:

  1. A firm has fixed costs, \(f\)
  2. A firm has constant marginal costs, \(MC(q)=c\) where \(c\geq0\)

If this is the case, then we can show that average costs are strictly decreasing over all output \(q\geq0\).

Again, we can integrate marginal cost to the total cost function (but here we need the arbitrary constant from integration, which we shall label \(f\), for fixed costs): \(C(q)=cq+f\). We can then find the average cost:

\[\begin{align*} C(q)&=cq+f\\ AC(q)=\frac{C(q)}{q}&=\frac{cq+f}{q}\\ AC(q)&=c+\frac{f}{q}\\ \end{align*}\]

Since \(f>0\), as \(q \rightarrow \infty\), \(AC(q) \rightarrow c\), that is, average cost is getting asymptotically close to marginal cost, \(c\), but will never intersect it. Note, I also included AFC, which again is always decreasing, and asymptotically approaching 0.

The importance of this type of cost structure is that it creates economies of scale, and represents a lot of industries that tend towards natural monopoly.


  1. Since we assumed there are no fixed costs, then there is no arbitrary constant from integration.↩︎

Previous
Next