Simple algebra to find equilibrium prices and quantities if we know supply and demand functions
Remember, supply and demand are each mathematical functions relating price to quantity:
We know at equilibrium: qD=qS
Example: Let the supply and demand functions for a market be:
qD=30−0.5pqS=2p−40
Find equilibrium quantity and price (q⋆,p⋆).
Sketch a rough graph.
Example: Let the supply and demand functions for a market be:
qD=30−0.5pqS=2p−40
Find equilibrium quantity and price (q⋆,p⋆).
Sketch a rough graph.
Markets allocate resources based on individuals’ reservation prices:
Goods flow to those who value them the highest and away from those who value them the lowest
Markets allocate resources based on individuals’ reservation prices:
Goods flow to those who value them the highest and away from those who value them the lowest
It might look like it, but competition in markets is NOT between buyers vs. sellers!
In markets:
Buyers want to pay the lowest price to buy a good
But they face competition from other buyers over the same scarce goods
Buyers attempt to raise their bids above others' reservation prices to obtain the goods
Sellers want to get the highest price for a good they sell
But they face competition from other sellers over the same potential customers
Sellers attempt to lower their asking prices below others' reservation prices to sell their goods
Imagine a small public horse market
3 people, A, B, and C each own 1 horse
3 people, D, E, and F each are potentially interested in buying a horse
This example is based on Eugen von Bohm-Bawerk’s famous example in Capital and Interest (1884)
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Imagine a small public horse market
3 people, A, B, and C each own 1 horse
3 people, D, E, and F each are potentially interested in buying a horse
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $400
Suppose Buyer F announces she will pay $400 for a horse
Only Seller A is willing to sell at $400
Buyers D, E, and F are willing to buy at $400
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $600
Suppose Seller C announces he will sell his horse for $600
Only Buyer D is willing to buy at $600
Sellers A, B, and C are willing to sell at $600
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
If the market price reaches $500 (through bids and asks changing):
Sellers A and B sell their horses for $500 each
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
At $500, B and E are the “marginal” buyer and seller, the “last” ones that just got off the fence to exchange in the market
The marginal pair actually are the ones that “set” the market price!
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
Notice the most possible exchanges take place at a market price of $500
Any price above or below $500, only 1 horse would get exchanged
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
At $500, A and D are the "inframarginal" buyers and sellers
These buyers and sellers benefit the most from exchange
Demand function measures how much you would hypothetically be willing to pay for various quantities
You often actually pay (the market-clearing price, p∗) a lot less than your reservation price
The difference is consumer surplus
CS=WTP−p∗
CS=12bhCS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS′=12bhCS′=12(3−0)($10−$7)CS′=$4.50
CS′=12bhCS′=12(7−0)($10−$3)CS′=$24.50
CS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS=12(5−0)($7−$5)CS=$5.00
Supply function measures how much you would hypothetically be willing to accept to sell various quantities
You often actually receive (the market-clearing price, p∗) a lot more than your reservation price
The difference is producer surplus
PS=p∗−WTA
PS=12bhPS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS′=12bhPS′=12(7−0)($7−$0)PS′=$24.50
PS′=12bhPS′=12(3−0)($3−$0)PS′=$4.50
PS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS=12(5−0)($5−$3)PS=$5.00
The more elastic curve at p∗ generates less surplus
The less elastic curve at p∗ generates more surplus
This is important for policies such as price controls, taxes, etc.
A good visual rule of thumb:
Compare distance between choke price and p∗ for each curve
Bigger distance ⟹ less elastic in equilibrium (and vice versa)
Example: Using last class's supply and demand functions:
qD=10−pqS=2p−8
Calculate the price elasticity of demand and the price elasticity of supply in equilibrium.
Calculate the consumer surplus and producer surplus. Shade each on the graph.
Who gets more surplus, consumers or producers, and why?
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
o | Tile View: Overview of Slides |
Esc | Back to slideshow |
Simple algebra to find equilibrium prices and quantities if we know supply and demand functions
Remember, supply and demand are each mathematical functions relating price to quantity:
We know at equilibrium: qD=qS
Example: Let the supply and demand functions for a market be:
qD=30−0.5pqS=2p−40
Find equilibrium quantity and price (q⋆,p⋆).
Sketch a rough graph.
Example: Let the supply and demand functions for a market be:
qD=30−0.5pqS=2p−40
Find equilibrium quantity and price (q⋆,p⋆).
Sketch a rough graph.
Markets allocate resources based on individuals’ reservation prices:
Goods flow to those who value them the highest and away from those who value them the lowest
Markets allocate resources based on individuals’ reservation prices:
Goods flow to those who value them the highest and away from those who value them the lowest
It might look like it, but competition in markets is NOT between buyers vs. sellers!
In markets:
Buyers want to pay the lowest price to buy a good
But they face competition from other buyers over the same scarce goods
Buyers attempt to raise their bids above others' reservation prices to obtain the goods
Sellers want to get the highest price for a good they sell
But they face competition from other sellers over the same potential customers
Sellers attempt to lower their asking prices below others' reservation prices to sell their goods
Imagine a small public horse market
3 people, A, B, and C each own 1 horse
3 people, D, E, and F each are potentially interested in buying a horse
This example is based on Eugen von Bohm-Bawerk’s famous example in Capital and Interest (1884)
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Imagine a small public horse market
3 people, A, B, and C each own 1 horse
3 people, D, E, and F each are potentially interested in buying a horse
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $400
Suppose Buyer F announces she will pay $400 for a horse
Only Seller A is willing to sell at $400
Buyers D, E, and F are willing to buy at $400
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $600
Suppose Seller C announces he will sell his horse for $600
Only Buyer D is willing to buy at $600
Sellers A, B, and C are willing to sell at $600
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
If the market price reaches $500 (through bids and asks changing):
Sellers A and B sell their horses for $500 each
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
At $500, B and E are the “marginal” buyer and seller, the “last” ones that just got off the fence to exchange in the market
The marginal pair actually are the ones that “set” the market price!
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
Notice the most possible exchanges take place at a market price of $500
Any price above or below $500, only 1 horse would get exchanged
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
Person | Reservation Price |
---|---|
A | Minimum WTA: $400 |
B | Minimum WTA: $500 |
C | Minimum WTA: $600 |
D | Maximum WTP: $600 |
E | Maximum WTP: $500 |
F | Maximum WTP: $400 |
Price: $500
At $500, A and D are the "inframarginal" buyers and sellers
These buyers and sellers benefit the most from exchange
Demand function measures how much you would hypothetically be willing to pay for various quantities
You often actually pay (the market-clearing price, p∗) a lot less than your reservation price
The difference is consumer surplus
CS=WTP−p∗
CS=12bhCS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS′=12bhCS′=12(3−0)($10−$7)CS′=$4.50
CS′=12bhCS′=12(7−0)($10−$3)CS′=$24.50
CS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS=12(5−0)($10−$5)CS=$12.50
CS=12(5−0)($7−$5)CS=$5.00
Supply function measures how much you would hypothetically be willing to accept to sell various quantities
You often actually receive (the market-clearing price, p∗) a lot more than your reservation price
The difference is producer surplus
PS=p∗−WTA
PS=12bhPS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS′=12bhPS′=12(7−0)($7−$0)PS′=$24.50
PS′=12bhPS′=12(3−0)($3−$0)PS′=$4.50
PS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS=12(5−0)($5−$0)PS=$12.50
PS=12(5−0)($5−$3)PS=$5.00
The more elastic curve at p∗ generates less surplus
The less elastic curve at p∗ generates more surplus
This is important for policies such as price controls, taxes, etc.
A good visual rule of thumb:
Compare distance between choke price and p∗ for each curve
Bigger distance ⟹ less elastic in equilibrium (and vice versa)
Example: Using last class's supply and demand functions:
qD=10−pqS=2p−8
Calculate the price elasticity of demand and the price elasticity of supply in equilibrium.
Calculate the consumer surplus and producer surplus. Shade each on the graph.
Who gets more surplus, consumers or producers, and why?